Dealing with the Leftovers: Residual Seasonality in GDP

October 19, 2018

KEY TAKEAWAYS

  • In recent decades, GDP growth in the first quarter has been substantially weaker than growth in other quarters, even after adjusting for typical seasonality.
  • This phenomenon, called residual seasonality, makes it difficult for policymakers to know whether a weak first quarter is due to an actual downturn or an understated number.
  • Another economic measure—gross domestic income—provides additional information for policymakers to determine whether the first-quarter GDP number reflects actual conditions.
Shoveling snow off sidewalk

Over the past few decades, one pronounced characteristic of gross domestic product (GDP) is that its growth rate during the first quarter of the year has been substantially lower than the growth rate during other quarters, even after adjusting for the typical seasonality.

This pattern can be seen in Figure 1, which shows the average growth rate of GDP for each of the four quarters for different periods: 2005-2009, 2010-2014 and 2015-2018. In each period, average GDP growth is markedly lower in the first quarter.

Figure 1

Gross Domestic Product Growth by Quarter

During 2005-2009, GDP growth in the first quarter averaged around 0.25 percent, a fraction of the average growth rate of other quarters in the same period. The discrepancy worsened in the 2010-2014 period. First-quarter GDP averaged around 1 percent in these years, while the other quarters’ growth rates were much higher—around 2.5 percent.

Economists have dubbed this phenomenon “residual seasonality,” suggesting that the published first-quarter GDP growth rate is artificially low and that actual growth is more in line with that of the other quarters. Residual seasonality has even been recognized by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), which has made efforts to correct it in the most recent comprehensive revisions to GDP.

Residual seasonality presents a problem for both forecasters and policymakers attempting to make timely evaluations of the economy. If the first-quarter GDP number appears to be low even after adjusting for typical seasonal patterns, how should the policymaker react? If the number has a residual seasonal component that is keeping it artificially low, policy actions that take the understated value as true could overstimulate an economy that is otherwise doing well. On the other hand, not reacting to a truly low number—under the belief that it is only a manifestation of a remaining seasonal component—could put the Federal Reserve in danger of being behind the curve.

What Is Residual Seasonality?

Before addressing residual seasonality, one first has to understand seasonality in general and why it is removed from economic data. Economic data have predictable variation throughout the year, caused by weather, regularly timed events (e.g., summer vacation) and holidays, and the seasonal nature of production (e.g., agriculture).

Economists call this predictable variation “seasonality” and usually remove it to compare the data across consecutive quarters. For example, nonseasonally adjusted fourth-quarter GDP in the U.S. tends to be higher than third-quarter GDP, when people often save for the holidays. Thus, a decrease in nonseasonally adjusted GDP from the second quarter to the third quarter would be predictable; however, without this knowledge, a decrease might instead look like the beginning of a recession. Further, large seasonal fluctuations overshadow the important movements in the underlying trend, which policymakers must identify to make decisions.

While some features of weather are predictable (e.g., people go out less in winter when it is colder), unusually severe weather events are not accounted for during seasonal adjustment. These events include catastrophic events, such as hurricanes and blizzards. Typically, economists view these events as temporary disruptions that shift consumption or production to a later time period. For example, a hurricane on the East Coast might cause a shift in production from one quarter to the next. However, these events are not generally predictable and do not occur every year. Thus, they would not be removed as part of seasonal adjustment.

Residual seasonality, like seasonality in general, is a predictable pattern of output that occurs over the year, but current methods are failing to measure it. Thus, residual seasonality is not removed in the initial seasonal adjustment process. As might be gleaned from its name, residual seasonality is the leftover seasonality that remains in already deseasonalized data.

Why Might Residual Seasonality Exist?

GDP data are collected by the BEA. Because elements of GDP are available at different times, the BEA collects components of GDP (e.g., consumption, investment) and aggregates them into the final number. Across the quarter, the BEA releases estimates of the data, some of which involve projections of GDP components. The data are seasonally adjusted using a complex algorithm developed by the Census Bureau that removes both the trend and seasonal components from the raw data.

One might think that the BEA collects the data on the components, aggregates them and then seasonally adjusts the aggregate. For various reasons, however, the BEA instead chooses to deseasonalize the components of GDP. Moreover, the BEA does not deseasonalize all the components of GDP. Several economists have independently identified the same residual seasonal patterns in nonresidential structures, government consumption and exports components of GDP, supporting the idea that small seasonalities unaccounted for in the components could be producing noticeable seasonal patterns in the aggregate.These components are not necessarily the components that are unadjusted by the BEA.

How Important Is Residual Seasonality?

Residual seasonality introduces additional uncertainty for policymakers. One way to measure the potential impact of low first-quarter data on policy rates is to use the Taylor rule, a standard policy tool that suggests an interest rate based on inflation and the actual level of GDP relative to potential GDP.

Economists at the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco and the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland estimate that first-quarter residual seasonality over the past 10 years ranges from –0.8 to –1.5 percent.See Lunsford, and Rudebusch et al. If first-quarter GDP were reported as 1 percent lower than the actual value due to residual seasonality, the output gap would widen, which could mean dropping rates by 0.5 percentage point under the Taylor rule. But policymakers, aware of residual seasonality, wouldn’t react, thus keeping rates higher than recommended by the Taylor rule.The impact of residual seasonality on the policy rule is muted, however, as the policy rule is based on the output gap, which considers the level of reported GDP relative to potential GDP.

Still, policymakers seeking to make the most timely adjustments to interest rates could try to reduce the effect of residual seasonality by looking at additional indicators of aggregate activity that are not subject to the same magnitude of residual seasonality.

The BEA tested both GDP and gross domestic income (GDI) for residual seasonality and found that while GDP does exhibit residual seasonality, GDI does not.See the BEA’s report on residual seasonality, www.bea.gov/research/papers/2016/residual-seasonality-gdp-and-gdi-findings-and-next-steps. 

GDI is another measure of total economic output. The two measures are theoretically equivalent; GDI measures economic activity in terms of income earned, and GDP measures in terms of production. They differ slightly in practice because of differences in source data. GDP is the more common measure because the GDI source data are released on a less timely basis than the GDP data, and the GDI sources are more difficult to map into higher frequency components (e.g., GDP can be traced to monthly personal consumption expenditures).

Figure 2

Gross Domestic Income Growth by Quarter

Figure 2 plots the average growth rates in GDI by quarter for the same time periods as shown in Figure 1. During the first two periods, first-quarter GDI growth is only slightly lower than second-quarter GDI growth and is much higher than first-quarter GDP growth in the same periods, as seen in Figure 1. During the last period, GDI growth is actually higher in the first quarter than the other quarters.

Looking at GDI growth in addition to GDP growth gives the policymaker additional information on economic activity. If the policymaker observes a relatively low first-quarter GDP number and a GDI number that is more in line with expectations, it is likely that the GDP number is understated because of residual seasonality. By observing GDI along with GDP, the policymaker can make a more informed decision regarding policy rates.

Endnotes

  1. These components are not necessarily the components that are unadjusted by the BEA.
  2. See Lunsford, and Rudebusch et al.
  3. The impact of residual seasonality on the policy rule is muted, however, as the policy rule is based on the output gap, which considers the level of reported GDP relative to potential GDP.
  4. See the BEA’s report on residual seasonality, www.bea.gov/research/papers/2016/residual-seasonality-gdp-and-gdi-findings-and-next-steps.

References

Boldin, Michael; and Wright, Jonathan H. Weather-Adjusting Economic Data. Brookings Panel on Economic Activity, Fall 2015, pp. 227-78.

Gilbert, Charles; Morin, Norman; Paciorek, Andrew D.; and Sahm, Claudia R. Residual Seasonality in GDP. FEDS Notes, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, May 14, 2015.

Groen, Jan; and Russo, Patrick. The Myth of First-Quarter Residual Seasonality. Liberty Street Economics, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, June 8, 2015.

Kliesen, Kevin L. Residual Seasonality: The Return of an Old First-Quarter Friend? On The Economy Blog, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, March 27, 2017.

Lunsford, Kurt G. Lingering Residual Seasonality in GDP Growth. Economic Commentary, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, March 28, 2017.

Moulton, Brent R.; and Cowan, Benjamin D. Residual Seasonality in GDP and GDI: Findings and Next Steps. Survey of Current Business, July 2016, Vol. 96, No. 7.

Rudebusch, Glenn D.; Wilson, Daniel J.; and Mahedy, Tim. The Puzzle of Weak First-Quarter GDP Growth. FRBSF Economic Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, May 18, 2015.

Rudebusch, Glenn D.; Wilson, Daniel J.; and Pyle, Benjamin. Residual Seasonality and Monetary Policy. FRBSF Economic Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Aug. 24, 2015.

Schwartz, Nelson. G.D.P. Report Shows U.S. Economy Off to Slow Start in 2017. The New York Times, April 28, 2017.

Sparshott, Jeffrey. Why First-Quarter Growth Is Often Weak. The Wall Street Journal, April 25, 2017.

About the Authors
Mike Owyang
Michael T. Owyang

Michael T. Owyang is an economist and senior economic policy advisor at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. His research focuses on business cycles and time series econometrics. He joined the St. Louis Fed in 2000. Read more about the author and his research.

Mike Owyang
Michael T. Owyang

Michael T. Owyang is an economist and senior economic policy advisor at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. His research focuses on business cycles and time series econometrics. He joined the St. Louis Fed in 2000. Read more about the author and his research.

Hannah Shell
Hannah Shell

Hannah G. Shell is a senior research associate at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

Hannah Shell
Hannah Shell

Hannah G. Shell is a senior research associate at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

Related Topics

Views expressed in Regional Economist are not necessarily those of the St. Louis Fed or Federal Reserve System.


For the latest insights from our economists and other St. Louis Fed experts, visit On the Economy and subscribe.


Email Us

Media questions

Back to Top