How Tight Is the Labor Market?

Monday, November 02, 2015
labor market slack
Thinkstock/rilueda

By Stephen Williamson, Vice President and Economist

This post is the first of a two-part series exploring slack in the labor market. The second post, “Labor Market Slack and the Insured Unemployment Rate” will appear on Tuesday, Nov. 3.

In some discussions of the current state of the U.S. labor market, it is argued that there is more “slack” in U.S. labor markets than might be apparent. For example, some argue that the unemployment rate, which stood at 5.1 percent in September, does not fully reflect hidden unemployed, such as discouraged workers (those who have stopped searching for work and have dropped out of the labor force) and those who are working part time but would prefer to work full time.

In modern models of labor market search,1 which help economists explain labor market behavior, a typical measure of labor market tightness is the ratio v/u, where v is the number of vacancies posted in the labor market and u is the number of unemployed. According to this measure, which is depicted in the following figure, the labor market is tighter the greater the number of firms seeking to fill jobs relative to the number of would-be workers looking for jobs.

By this measure, the U.S. labor market is as tight as it has been at any time between the past two recessions.

Another way to look at labor market tightness is to plot the labor market vacancy rate against the unemployment rate. Such a scatter plot traces out what is known as the Beveridge curve, depicted in the next figure.

In this scatter plot, the line joins observations from December 2000 to July 2015, from the top left-hand corner to the lower right-hand corner, and back. A key feature of the scatter plot is the curve’s shift to the right that occurred during the Great Recession (December 2007 through June 2009). Some economists have argued that this shift is due to “mismatch unemployment.”2 The idea is that the Great Recession created a greater mismatch between the skills desired by firms and the skills offered on the market by would-be workers.

One can, in part, explain the shift in the Beveridge curve by decomposing unemployment by duration. That is, the shift in the curve seems to be due to a large increase in the number of long-term unemployed that occurred during the Great Recession. This is consistent with the mismatch idea, as unemployed people subject to the mismatch problem tend to be unemployed a long time.

Indeed, one dimension of labor market performance that has not returned to levels which we would consider normal before the Great Recession is long-term unemployment. The next figure shows the number of unemployed for 27 weeks or more.

According to the figure, the number of long-term unemployed is still larger than at any time between the past two recessions. Another important observation relates to the flow of workers each month from the unemployment pool to not-in-the-labor-force (NILF). These are workers who have been searching for work, and then stopped searching and left the labor force. If we plot this flow against the number of long-term unemployed, we obtain the next figure.

The key takeaway from this figure is that flows from unemployment to NILF tend to be positively correlated with the number of long-term unemployed. Basically, the long-term unemployed are relatively highly likely to drop out of the labor force.

Therefore, if we think of the long-term unemployed as being subject to the mismatch problem and highly likely to leave the labor force, then these unemployed workers are not contributing much to labor market slack. They are unlikely to be hired under any conditions.

Going back to the third figure, there are currently about 1 million more long-term unemployed than there were in late 2007 before the Great Recession began. If we think that the quantity of long-term unemployed will return to 2007 levels, then roughly 1 million of those currently unemployed may be leaving the labor force. If we count those 1 million people as NILF rather than unemployed, the unemployment rate would be 4.6 percent, rather than 5.1 percent. We might then think of 4.6 percent as more accurately reflecting the state of unemployment in the labor market, rather than 5.1 percent.

Additional measures of unemployment also show that labor markets may be tighter than most may assume. In tomorrow’s post, we’ll look at a nonstandard measure of unemployment: the insured unemployment rate.

Notes and References

1 For example, see Shimer, Robert. “The Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium Unemployment and Vacancies,” American Economic Review, March 2005, Vol. 95, Issue 1, pp. 25-49.

2 For example, see Sahin, Aysegül; Song, Joseph; Topa, Giorgio; and Violante, Giovanni. “Mismatch Unemployment,” American Economic Review, forthcoming.

Additional Resources

Posted In Labor  |  Tagged stephen williamsonlaborbeveridge curvelong term unemployedlabor market slack
Commenting Policy: We encourage comments and discussions on our posts, even those that disagree with conclusions, if they are done in a respectful and courteous manner. All comments posted to our blog go through a moderator, so they won't appear immediately after being submitted. We reserve the right to remove or not publish inappropriate comments. This includes, but is not limited to, comments that are:
  • Vulgar, obscene, profane or otherwise disrespectful or discourteous
  • For commercial use, including spam
  • Threatening, harassing or constituting personal attacks
  • Violating copyright or otherwise infringing on third-party rights
  • Off-topic or significantly political
The St. Louis Fed will only respond to comments if we are clarifying a point. Comments are limited to 1,500 characters, so please edit your thinking before posting. While you will retain all of your ownership rights in any comment you submit, posting comments means you grant the St. Louis Fed the royalty-free right, in perpetuity, to use, reproduce, distribute, alter and/or display them, and the St. Louis Fed will be free to use any ideas, concepts, artwork, inventions, developments, suggestions or techniques embodied in your comments for any purpose whatsoever, with or without attribution, and without compensation to you. You will also waive all moral rights you may have in any comment you submit.
comments powered by Disqus

The St. Louis Fed uses Disqus software for the comment functionality on this blog. You can read the Disqus privacy policy. Disqus uses cookies and third party cookies. To learn more about these cookies and how to disable them, please see this article.

Subscribe to
On the Economy

Get notified when new content is available on our On the Economy blog.

Email Alerts  |  RSS

About the Blog

The St. Louis Fed On the Economy blog features relevant commentary, analysis, research and data from our economists and other St. Louis Fed experts.


Views expressed are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis or of the Federal Reserve System.

Contact Us

For media-related questions, email mediainquiries@stls.frb.org. For all other blog-related questions or comments, email on-the-economy@stls.frb.org.

Categories