The Effects of Contract Enforcement and Corruption on Trade

Thursday, May 28, 2015
contracts, corruption, trade
Thinkstock/mangsaab

The role that institutions play in facilitating trade is receiving increasing attention. A recent article in The Regional Economist examined two indicators of the effects institutions can have: contract enforcement and corruption.

Research Officer and Economist Subhayu Bandyopadhyay and Senior Research Associate Yang Liu, both with the St. Louis Fed, and Suryadipta Roy, an assistant professor of economics at High Point University, explained how each of these institutional factors may affect trade and discussed studies that related to each factor.

Contract Intensity

The authors provided an example of goods manufacturers and their suppliers to show why contract enforcement matters. Some goods require specialized parts to be produced. These parts are considered contract-intensive, as satisfaction of the contract terms for delivery becomes important in ensuring timely and efficient production of the final good.

Weak judicial systems mean contracts between the manufacturers and their suppliers may not be properly enforced, which could drive the costs of supplied goods up. The firms needing these goods will end up importing them, while exporting other goods.

A 2014 study by economists Nathan Nunn and Daniel Trefler showed that advanced economies, which usually have better institutions, undertake production and exports of sophisticated, high-quality products (which are more contract-intensive by their very nature) to a greater extent compared with low-income countries.1 Also, the high-income countries with similar institutional structures traded disproportionally more with one another than with low-income countries.

Corruption

The authors noted that countries with high levels of corruption are characterized by burdensome regulations, which are exploited by dishonest officials to extract bribes from traders, thereby driving up the costs of trade. A 2007 study by Bandyopadhyay and Roy found that greater corruption significantly increased import duties and other related taxes, while reducing the trade to gross domestic product ratios of the respective nations.2

Conclusion

The authors concluded, “What is clear from our discussion is that the literature in international trade has reached a consensus that improved institutions facilitate trade and that production of more-sophisticated products requires better institutions. Keeping these two issues in mind, developing nations have to find ways to improve their institutions. This is a complex problem, especially for developing nations facing resource constraints.”

Notes and References

1 Nunn, Nathan; and Trefler, Daniel. “Domestic Institutions as a Source of Comparative Advantage,” Handbook of International Economics, April 2014, Vol. 4, pp. 263-315.

2 Bandyopadhyay, Subhayu; and Roy, Suryadipta. “Corruption and Trade Protection: Evidence from Panel Data,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper 2007-22A, May 2007.

Additional Resources

Posted In Trade  |  Tagged subhayu bandyopadhyayyang liutradecorruption
Commenting Policy: We encourage comments and discussions on our posts, even those that disagree with conclusions, if they are done in a respectful and courteous manner. All comments posted to our blog go through a moderator, so they won't appear immediately after being submitted. We reserve the right to remove or not publish inappropriate comments. This includes, but is not limited to, comments that are:
  • Vulgar, obscene, profane or otherwise disrespectful or discourteous
  • For commercial use, including spam
  • Threatening, harassing or constituting personal attacks
  • Violating copyright or otherwise infringing on third-party rights
  • Off-topic or significantly political
The St. Louis Fed will only respond to comments if we are clarifying a point. Comments are limited to 1,500 characters, so please edit your thinking before posting. While you will retain all of your ownership rights in any comment you submit, posting comments means you grant the St. Louis Fed the royalty-free right, in perpetuity, to use, reproduce, distribute, alter and/or display them, and the St. Louis Fed will be free to use any ideas, concepts, artwork, inventions, developments, suggestions or techniques embodied in your comments for any purpose whatsoever, with or without attribution, and without compensation to you. You will also waive all moral rights you may have in any comment you submit.
comments powered by Disqus

The St. Louis Fed uses Disqus software for the comment functionality on this blog. You can read the Disqus privacy policy. Disqus uses cookies and third party cookies. To learn more about these cookies and how to disable them, please see this article.

Subscribe to
On the Economy

Get notified when new content is available on our On the Economy blog.

Email Alerts  |  RSS

About the Blog

The St. Louis Fed On the Economy blog features relevant commentary, analysis, research and data from our economists and other St. Louis Fed experts.


Views expressed are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis or of the Federal Reserve System.

Contact Us

For media-related questions, email mediainquiries@stls.frb.org. For all other blog-related questions or comments, email on-the-economy@stls.frb.org.

Categories