The Link between Default and Depreciation

Monday, August 25, 2014

By David Wiczer, Economist

In the aftermath of the Argentine default (or semi-default, depending on how you look at it), the Argentine peso has fallen considerably, with reports of market expectations that the default would cause 11 percent depreciation in the currency.1

One should not take for granted, however, that currency markets and sovereign debt markets would be inexorably tied: The Argentine peso trades on international markets to facilitate mostly private-sector trade between Argentina and the rest of the world, while Argentine sovereign debt is issued for the government to borrow and its default is a reflection of the public-sector finances. Why is this link so intimate? Are there implications of this linkage?

This idea will be fleshed out further, but in this post I will posit that currency depreciation acts as a punishment for default. It makes imports from the rest of the world more expensive and hurts consumers in Argentina. Because this effect is relatively predictable, it acts as a deterrent to default, which in turn makes default less likely and increases countries’ borrowing ability.

The table below shows that the relationship between currency depreciation and default is rather strong and predictable. In this table, we take the record of defaults (as categorized by Standard & Poor’s since 1970) and look at how their exchange rates and trade flows changed. There is obviously variation across countries’ experiences, and so the table shows that the vast majority experience some depreciation. Note the depreciation occurs when looking at both nominal and real terms of trade: This is not just an effect of faster inflation in the defaulting country but rather a change in the terms of trade.

Argentina default

Why would default cause depreciation? Sovereign default on foreign currency debt makes foreign creditors reluctant to deal with borrowers of all sorts from defaulting countries. And because importers and exporters from defaulting countries require some short-term credit to facilitate trade, defaults can increase the risk in the trade and hence turn prices against them.

Locals may also look to hold more foreign currency as a precaution, because government willingness to default on debt, even only in foreign markets, makes assets like government bonds denominated in the local currency less valuable.

Depreciation has two distinct effects on local economies:

  • Foreign goods become more expensive to import.
  • Locally produced substitutes become relatively cheaper.

Hence, the depreciation both hurts consumers and can spur some increase in production. The relative importance of imports to the local basket of purchases can, therefore, be a factor in how much default hurts. This cost of default is not trivial, because the costs of sovereign default are generally ill-defined. A personal default has certain legal pathways that are generally well defined, but this is not so when a country stops paying.

When considering how much to lend and at what interest rates, lenders need to consider the countries’ likelihood of repaying, and this involves calculating how much it would hurt countries to default. In short, harsher punishments can increase access to foreign credit because countries are less likely to default if that would be more painful. Depreciation is truly a double-edged sword, serving as the punishment that allays lenders’ fears of default, but also hurting the ordinary bystanders to a government’s actions in the case of default.

Notes and References

1 Porzecanski, Katia. “Argentine Default Sours Outlook for Peso as Talks Ordered.” Bloomberg Businessweek, Aug. 4, 2014. It should be noted that this article also cited a JPMorgan projection that the government might intervene in currency markets to prop up its peso and make the default appear less legitimate.

Additional Resources

Posted In FinancialTrade  |  Tagged argentinadavid wiczerdefault
Commenting Policy: We encourage comments and discussions on our posts, even those that disagree with conclusions, if they are done in a respectful and courteous manner. All comments posted to our blog go through a moderator, so they won't appear immediately after being submitted. We reserve the right to remove or not publish inappropriate comments. This includes, but is not limited to, comments that are:
  • Vulgar, obscene, profane or otherwise disrespectful or discourteous
  • For commercial use, including spam
  • Threatening, harassing or constituting personal attacks
  • Violating copyright or otherwise infringing on third-party rights
  • Off-topic or significantly political
The St. Louis Fed will only respond to comments if we are clarifying a point. Comments are limited to 1,500 characters, so please edit your thinking before posting. While you will retain all of your ownership rights in any comment you submit, posting comments means you grant the St. Louis Fed the royalty-free right, in perpetuity, to use, reproduce, distribute, alter and/or display them, and the St. Louis Fed will be free to use any ideas, concepts, artwork, inventions, developments, suggestions or techniques embodied in your comments for any purpose whatsoever, with or without attribution, and without compensation to you. You will also waive all moral rights you may have in any comment you submit.
comments powered by Disqus

The St. Louis Fed uses Disqus software for the comment functionality on this blog. You can read the Disqus privacy policy. Disqus uses cookies and third party cookies. To learn more about these cookies and how to disable them, please see this article.

Subscribe to
On the Economy

Get notified when new content is available on our On the Economy blog.

Email Alerts  |  RSS

About the Blog

The St. Louis Fed On the Economy blog features relevant commentary, analysis, research and data from our economists and other St. Louis Fed experts.


Views expressed are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis or of the Federal Reserve System.

Contact Us

For media-related questions, email mediainquiries@stls.frb.org. For all other blog-related questions or comments, email on-the-economy@stls.frb.org.

Categories