U.S. Barriers to International Trade of Goods: Tariffs and Non-Tariff Measures

April 28, 2023

International trade can be critical for economic growth and development, connecting countries and businesses across the world.There are certainly some costs of trade, particularly during periods of transition following policy changes. Yet the long-run effects of trade on growth and development are overwhelmingly estimated to be positive. While trade barriers have consistently decreased in recent decades, leading to the unprecedented growth of trade linkages, significant barriers remain across countries: The U.S. is no exception. Barriers hinder the free flow of goods and services between countries and hurt economies and consumers alike. In this essay, we document the prevalence of barriers to international trade in the U.S.

One challenge when characterizing the extent of barriers in a given country is the variety of policies through which countries may limit trade. Here, we take a comprehensive look at trade barriers in the U.S. by partitioning policies into two types: tariffs and non-tariff measures (NTMs).United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. “International Classification of Non-Tariff Measures” (PDF). 2019. Tariffs are taxes on imports expressed as a percentage of the total value imported, effectively raising the price of imports and making domestic substitutes more attractive. Non-tariff measures encompass a broad range of policies and regulations that can also limit the free flow of goods, such as quotas, licenses, and technical standards.

We document the prevalence of these policies in the U.S. using data for 2014 collected by the World Bank and the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, which are publicly available through the Trade Analysis Information System and World Integrated Trade Solution.World Integrated Trade Solution. “Tariff and Trade Analysis” and “United States Non-Tariff Measure Statistics.”

Figure 1: Comparison of Tariff and Non-Tariff Measures across Industries

Figure 1 (A) shows tariffs and Figure 1 (B) shows non-tariff measures, or NTMs, expressed as a percent. Industries shown are: Wood, Machinery/Electrical, Misc., Chemicals, Metals, Stone/Glass, Animal, Vegetable, Transportation, Plastic or Rubber, Minerals, Food Products, Hides/Skins, Textiles/Clothing, and Footwear/Headgear.

SOURCE: World Integrated Trade Solution.

We analyze the prevalence of tariffs and NTMs in the U.S. across industries. Panel A of Figure 1 displays average ad valorem tariffs across industries. These values vary significantly across industries, from less than 1% in Wood and Machinery/Electrical to over 11% in Textiles and Footwear/Headgear. While explaining the sources underlying this variability is beyond the scope of this essay, they may be accounted for by using idiosyncratic sectoral characteristics such as their relative value, safety, or competition concerns. However, we observe that tariffs are relatively low on average, below 6% after excluding industries related to textiles.

Panel B of Figure 1 documents the prevalence of non-tariff measures in the U.S. One issue with NTMs is that the variety of instruments in place makes them harder to compare. Thus, for each industry, we report the coverage ratio: the share of industry-level imports subject to some type of NTM. One drawback of this measure is that it restricts attention to the share of goods subject to an NTM, abstracting from the intensity in which an industry distorts imports.Some papers have estimated values for the ad valorem equivalent costs of these NTM coverages. See Cadot, O. and Gourdon, J. “Non-Tariff Measures, Preferential Trade Agreements, and Prices: New Evidence.” Review of World Economics, 2016, 152, pp. 227-49. And see Kinzius, L.; Sandkamp, A. and Yalcin, E. “Trade Protection and the Role of Non-Tariff Barriers.” Review of World Economics, 2019, 155, pp. 603-43. In contrast to tariffs, NTMs are ubiquitous across U.S. imports in all industries. For instance, in half the industries, NTMs cover more than 70% of total imports. There is nevertheless significant variability across industries: Metals and Minerals have fairly low coverage, while Animals and Textiles/Clothing have over 90% of their import value covered by some form of NTM.

These findings suggest that NTMs may be a significant barrier to trade in the U.S. The intended goal of tariffs is to distort international trade flows, often in the interest of protecting domestic industries. In contrast, NTMs may be in place to achieve some other goal, and their distortions of international trade flows may just be collateral damage the U.S. pays to fulfill these other goals. For instance, NTMs are often introduced to regulate the safety of imports of medicine and food, ensuring imports satisfy domestic sanitary and phytosanitary (plant health) policies. Thus, in Figure 2 we disaggregate the prevalence of NTMs by type across (i) sanitary and phytosanitary measures, (ii) technical barriers to trade, (iii) pre-shipment inspection and other formalities, and (iv) charges, taxes, and other para-tariff measures. For simplicity, we restrict attention to a few selected industries and the aggregate of all industries to illustrate the overall patterns.

Figure 2: Non-Tariff Measure (NTM) Type Coverage by Select Sectors

Industries shown in series of bar charts are Metals, Machinery/Electrical, All Sectors, Textiles/Clothing, and Food Products. Description in article.

SOURCE: World Integrated Trade Solution.

NOTE: Numbers above the bars indicate the number of NTM subcategories covered within each type, for each sector.

We observe that the prevalence of NTMs varies significantly by type. While the total NTM coverage for all industries is over 75%, NTM coverage is close to 80% for technical barriers but less than 20% coverage for sanitary, inspection, and additional requirements. Technical barriers to trade include import authorizations and licensing, labeling and packaging requirements, and product quality and safety requirements. Some of these may be critical to ensure the safety of U.S. consumers, but others may be in place to limit the extent of international trade.

We also observe that the type of NTM in place varies widely across industries. On one hand, sanitary and phytosanitary requirements cover more than 90% of imports of food products but have no coverage of Metals, Machinery/Electrical, or Textiles/Clothing imports. This category includes requirements on hygiene standards, pest elimination treatments, and conformity assessments, which naturally apply to food products but are not relevant to the other sectors. On the other hand, technical NTMs cover more than 75% of imports of Machinery/Electrical. Again, some of these may be in place to ensure safety standards, but they may also reflect the goal of protecting domestic industries from foreign competition.For a further discussion on the reasoning behind NTM implementation, see Herghelegiu, C. “The Political Economy of Non-Tariff Measures.” World Economy, 2018 41(1), pp. 262-86.

This essay documents many ways international trade in the U.S. is obstructed beyond ad valorem tariffs. Even if NTMs are in place to address legitimate considerations, such as the safety of U.S. consumers and the quality of inputs used by U.S. firms, it is important to keep in mind that these policies also distort international trade flows, potentially hurting U.S. consumers and firms. While this phenomenon suggests a tradeoff between the safety/health/quality of U.S. imports and international trade barriers, this need not be the case. Countries can expand international trade agreements to ensure the standards of the goods traded: Economies with similar levels of economic development, such as the U.S. and Europe, could expand trade agreements to accept each other’s health and safety standards, thereby ensuring these ultimate goals are met and that trade is open.

Notes

  1. There are certainly some costs of trade, particularly during periods of transition following policy changes. Yet the long-run effects of trade on growth and development are overwhelmingly estimated to be positive.
  2. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. “International Classification of Non-Tariff Measures” (PDF). 2019.
  3. World Integrated Trade Solution. “Tariff and Trade Analysis” and “United States Non-Tariff Measure Statistics.”
  4. Some papers have estimated values for the ad valorem equivalent costs of these NTM coverages. See Cadot, O. and Gourdon, J. “Non-Tariff Measures, Preferential Trade Agreements, and Prices: New Evidence.” Review of World Economics, 2016, 152, pp. 227-49. And see Kinzius, L.; Sandkamp, A. and Yalcin, E. “Trade Protection and the Role of Non-Tariff Barriers.” Review of World Economics, 2019, 155, pp. 603-43.
  5. For a further discussion on the reasoning behind NTM implementation, see Herghelegiu, C. “The Political Economy of Non-Tariff Measures.” World Economy, 2018 41(1), pp. 262-86.

Note: This blog post originally appeared as an Economic Synopses essay. View the full Economic Synopses archive in FRASER, the St. Louis Fed’s digital library.

About the Authors
Fernando Leibovici
Fernando Leibovici

Fernando Leibovici is an economist and economic policy advisor at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. His research focuses on international trade, finance and macroeconomics. He joined the St. Louis Fed in 2016. Read more about the author and his work.

Fernando Leibovici
Fernando Leibovici

Fernando Leibovici is an economist and economic policy advisor at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. His research focuses on international trade, finance and macroeconomics. He joined the St. Louis Fed in 2016. Read more about the author and his work.

Jason Dunn
Jason Dunn

Jason Dunn was a research associate at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

Jason Dunn
Jason Dunn

Jason Dunn was a research associate at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

Related Topics

This blog offers commentary, analysis and data from our economists and experts. Views expressed are not necessarily those of the St. Louis Fed or Federal Reserve System.


Email Us

Media questions

All other blog-related questions

Back to Top